Professor Emeritus David Lim, Griffith University, Brisbane, Australia
One of the most important concepts in economics is comparative advantage—the ability to produce goods and services at a lower opportunity cost than others, which forms the basis for exchange. The Heckscher-Ohlin theory suggests that this ability comes from differences in factor endowments, where a country will do well producing goods and services that use relatively more of its abundant resource. Thus, a developing economy with abundant labour and little capital and technology should produce labour-intensive and low-technology goods. By implication, it should not offer investment incentives that subsidize capital. And whatever capital it has should be used to the full. This article looks back at the work I did on these issues from the mid-1970s for Malaysia.
Capital subsidies and capital intensity
Malaysia offered many incentives to attract investment, especially foreign direct investment (FDI), in the period under review. The operative legislation was the Investment Incentives Act of 1968. Its most important provision for firms that were granted ‘pioneer status’ was the tax holiday, whose duration depended on the level of investment, so the larger this was, the longer the firm paid no company tax. Added to this were accelerated capital depreciation, investment allowances, and subsidized bank loans, which directly subsidized capital expenditure. A priori, by reducing the cost of investment, these incentives would, other things being equal, encourage the establishment of capital-intensive activities. This is something that labour-abundant countries such as Malaysia should not do.
The data from Malaysia's 1972 Survey of Manufacturing conducted by the Department of Statistics–Malaysia, showed that pioneer firms were much more capital intensive than the rest at the industry-group level for 12 such groups. In general, empirical evidence shows that this greater capital intensity was caused by the provision of capital subsidies. 1A caveat of this simple two-variable regression is that large firms, especially foreign ones, might have been given capital subsidies even if they did not seek them because of their size and their degree of foreign ownership. If so, then just using capital subsidy would have introduced biases into the relationship, as it incorporated the effects of scale and reputation via their influence on the cost of capital.
It is obvious that as the size of firms increases, they are likely to be more capital intensive as it is easier to achieve quality control for mass production using ‘machine-paced’ rather than ‘operator-paced’ techniques of production when there is a shortage of skilled workers. The higher the degree of foreign ownership of the firms, the more likely they are more capital intensive because foreign firms prefer using the technology they are familiar with, regardless of factor cost and scale considerations. They could also be reluctant to get too involved in the social and political problems associated with employing local labour. I then re-estimated the simple two-variable regression by introducing the two additional variables mentioned above.
During this period, Malaysia’s five-year development plans, and those of many developing economies, were formulated on this basis. Once the needed investment level has been estimated, policies are introduced to increase the level of capital from domestic savings, FDI, and foreign aid, and to raise efficiency in its use. The corollary of a capital-centred approach to growth is that the capital available is utilized heavily. I was able to find if this was the case in 1973 in a World Bank project on capital utilization in manufacturing in Colombia, Israel, Malaysia, and the Philippines. The first thing we did was to seek an objective measure of capital utilization.
We rejected the widely used McGraw-Hill measure because production managers are not given a definition of full capacity when asked the percentage of full capacity at which they are operating their plants. For example, a firm that believes full capacity is 50 per cent of the total number of hours available in a day, after time is taken out for maintenance, will report a higher level of utilization than one that sees it as 67 per cent. We also rejected the electricity measure, where utilization is the percentage of the rated capacity of the electric motor plants used to drive the capital equipment. This
Concluding remarks
My analysis of national survey data suggested two main conclusions. First, Malaysia offered investment incentives that favoured capital, which resulted in more capital-intensive manufacturing activities than should be the case for what was at the time a labour-abundant and capital-scarce economy. Second, Malaysia had a low level of capital utilization for a country lacking capital. This seems ironic but it could help to explain why the investment-dependent duration of the tax holiday was dropped when the Investment Incentives Act of 1968 was replaced by the 1986 Promotion of Investments Act.
The provision of investment incentives also ironically did little to encourage FDI (Lim, 1983, pp. 207–212), a view shared by a Bank Negara Malaysia working paper (Mohd Shazwan Shuhaimen et al., 2017). FDI is decided fundamentally by proven economic performance and, where relevant, the presence of mineral deposits (Lim, 1983, pp. 207–212). Countries lacking these compete among themselves in giving more incentives, while all the time foreign firms decide where and how much to invest according to non-tax criteria, knowing full well that they would pay very little tax wherever they went (Shah and Toye, 1978).
Bautista, R., H. Hughes, D. Lim, D. Moratwez, and F. Thoumi. 1983. Capital Utilization in Manufacturing in Developing Countries. New York: Oxford University Press.
Fong, C. O. and K. C. Lim. 1984. ‘Investment Incentives and Trends in Manufacturing Investments in Malaysia’. The Developing Economies, v. 22, No. 4.
Lim, D. 1976a. ‘On the Measurement of Capital Utilisation in Less Developed Countries’. Oxford Economic Papers, v. 28, No. 1.
______ 1976b. ‘Capital Utilization of Local and Foreign Establishments in Malaysian Manufacturing’. Review of Economics and Statistics, v. 58, No. 2.
______ 1977a. ‘Actual, Desired and Full Levels of Capital Utilisation in Malaysian Manufacturing’. Journal of Development Studies, v. 14, No. 1.
______ 1977b. ‘Do Foreign Companies Pay Higher Wages Than Their Local Counterparts in Malaysian Manufacturing?’ Journal of Development Economics, v. 4, No. 1.
______ 1978. ‘Sweat Labour and Wages in Malaysian Manufacturing’. Economic Development and Cultural Change, v. 27, No. 1.
______ 1980. ‘Tax Incentives and Resource Utilisation in a Small LDC’. Australian Economic Papers, v. 19, No. 34.
______ 1981. ‘Another Look at the Effect of Capital Subsidies on Capital-Intensity’. Australian Economic Papers, v. 20, No. 37.
______ 1983. ‘Fiscal Incentives and Direct Foreign Investment in Less Developed Countries’. Journal of Development Studies, v. 19, No. 2.
______ 1992. ‘Capturing the Effects of Capital Subsidies’. Journal of Development Studies, v. 28, No. 4.
Mohd Shazwan Shuhaimen, Nurul Hana Ahmad Ghazali, K. T. F. Wong, P. L. Loke, and Sarah Syamimi Mohd Suhaimi. 2017. ‘Rethinking Investment Incentives’. Kuala Lumpur: Bank Negara Malaysia, Staff Insights 2017/12.
Shah. S. M. S. and J. Toye. 1978. ‘Fiscal Incentives for Firms in Some Developing Countries: Survey and Critique’ in J. Toye (ed.) Taxation and Economic Development. London: Frank Cass.